Daily Archives: October 3, 2011

The end of 2012 will mark a once in 20-year overlap of a presidential election in the US with a leadership transition in China. France also chooses its president in the spring of next year, Germany its chancellor later in 2013. Unfortunately, election year pressures threaten to complicate an already very difficult and unpredictable policy dynamic, particularly as the European crisis goes from bad to worse.

Ordinarily, a prospective clumping of elections might portend a classic political budget cycle. Anxious to please their constituencies, governments would be cutting taxes, raising transfers, and boosting spending on particularly visible projects. Their largesse would be financed not only by higher deficits, but also by deferring expenditures with less immediate visibility, and by levering the government balance sheet through off-budget loan guarantees and other non-transparent mechanisms. In earlier times, particularly before the advent of central bank independence, election year interest rate cuts might also be expected. The central bank would be timing stimulus so as to maximally impact pre-election output and employment, while hoping that the main effect on inflation would come later.

The late US president Richard Nixon is perhaps the all-time hero of political budget cycle researchers. In his 1972 re-election campaign, famous for the Watergate scandal, Mr Nixon left no stone unturned when it came to boosting transfers, spending and growth. He doubled social security benefit increases, and browbeat Federal Reserve chairman Arthur Burns into significantly increasing the money supply. Indeed many monetary scholars regard Mr Burns’ 20 per cent plus pre-election increase in the money supply as the real culprit for the inflation of the 1970s, not the Opec oil price increases as is commonly assumed.

It is a different story today. The world is still very much gripped by the aftermath of the financial crisis. The orgy of post-financial crisis spending and deficits has left both the public and investors wary of further red ink. More importantly, the prolonged period of slow growth has dramatically weakened incumbent governments. Few are commanding the kind of majority needed to engage in a Nixonian political budget cycle, even if it were desirable. Indeed, as highlighted both by this summer’s debilitating debt debate in the US, as well as by Europe’s continuing struggle with periphery insolvencies, macroeconomic policy is much closer to being paralysed, than to being manipulated.

In normal times, any dynamic that shut down the political business cycle might well be interpreted as a plus for longer-term stability and growth. But the risk of partisan political paralysis in the face of a potential euro crash is another matter. Imagine, for example, that US growth collapses so severely that once again a major financial company finds itself on the brink of bankruptcy. Will the Fed and the Treasury be able to prevent a full-scale panic and systemic collapse in a timely fashion? Perhaps, but pre-election paralysis might make the task even harder than it was in 2008, particularly thanks to Dodd-Frank legislation aimed at preventing bail-outs.

There is a presumption that China has both the will and the means to react forcefully to any global growth crisis, as it did in 2008. Having raised reserve requirements to over 21 per cent for the largest financial institutions, its central bank has ample scope for monetary easing. But even in China, the scope and timing could be complicated by the delicate dance between an outgoing government interested in ending on a strong note, and an incoming administration that may want to front-load badly needed rebalancing of demand.

In theory, central banks ought to be relatively immune to electioneering. In practice, however, central bank independence has its limits. The Fed has already come under severe political pressure from Republicans wary of further easing measures. It can resist such pressures, but it can hardly dismiss them. Congress ultimately controls over the Fed’s mandate and the president controls the appointment of governors. Given the highly skewed risks now facing the economy, it is absurd to be worrying excessively about a 1970s-style stagflation, though some continue to do so. The risks of a Japanese-style lost decade or even a second Great Depression are far more immediate. The Fed has very limited tools at its disposal, yet pre-election political pressures are constraining even these.

Similarly, the fact the European Central Bank has not already cut interest rates to zero reflects far more the need to preserve a semblance of independence than a sober calculation of the balance of risks. If the eurozone ultimately becomes unglued, will anyone care that during euro’s brief life, inflation expectations remained firmly anchored about 2 per cent?

The US, Europe and China all have big decisions to take over how their economies and societies are to be shaped in the future. If existing or new leaders emerge from the upcoming elections with a clear mandate, perhaps we will see the kind of structural reform that will help growth and stability over the longer term. But if the overhang of elections exacerbates paralysis around difficult policy decisions, it will create huge potential for amplification at the worst possible time. Even under the best scenario, 2012 promises to be a year of even greater politically-induced volatility than 2011.

The writer is professor of economics at Harvard University and co-author with Carmen M Reinhart of ‘This time is different’

Response by Olaf Cramme

Institutional change is vital if individual leadership is to return

Kenneth Rogoff puts the hook where it hurts most: not only has the economic crisis in the US and particularly in the eurozone turned political, but politics is now generally regarded as the major stumbling block to solving the problems. This is because politics invokes choices and trade-offs. Ideological polarisation and partisan promises can only increase uncertainty, delay important decisions, and favour short-sightedness. From this perspective, we need more technocratic governance, not less.

Present developments on both sides of the Atlantic seem to confirm Mr Rogoff’s fears. In the US, the Tea Party movement has acquired an agenda-setting power that would give any non-dogmatic policymaker a headache. In Europe, populism is now an established force of influence which politicians can no longer play down. For many citizens, the financial crash has revealed a deep crisis of democracy and legitimacy in our political systems. No wonder ideology is back on the table.

In this context, bold political leadership seems the only way out: taking the big, often unpopular decisions demanded by experts and the markets while responding to public concerns about representation and fairness. Unfortunately, this is unlikely to happen. Many have put the blame on today’s leaders, depicting weak personalities or their misguided priorities. Yet the actual reason may run much deeper: our present capitalist settlement has created degrees of economic interdependence which politicians find impossible to handle under domestic pressures and the prerogative of national sovereignty. The resulting tensions apply to both the world economy and the European Union. For individual leadership to return, institutional change is indispensable.

So what is likely to guide popular reaction in the years ahead? In Europe, at least, a majority of citizens seem to recognise that a credible solution to the unsustainable status quo is nowhere near. For the time being, they seem willing to settle for more technocratic governance. Indeed, it is no surprise that those politicians currently in high regard are centrist, competent managers with cross-party appeal: look at the popularity of Peer Steinbrück in Germany (the opponent German Chancellor Angela Merkel is said to fear most), or François Hollande, current frontrunner in the primaries of the Parti Socialiste and the likely rival of French President Nicolas Sarkozy.

Our political systems are undergoing radical change. Greater volatility, if not instability, could well be the ultimate consequence. Much will depend though on how successful the latest generation of “political engineers” will be.

The writer is director of Policy Network and a visiting fellow at the LSE’s European Institute.

The A-List

About this blog Blog guide
Welcome. This blog is available to subscribers only.

The A-List from the Financial Times provides timely, insightful comment on the topics that matter, from globally renowned leaders, policymakers and commentators.

Read the A-List author biographies

Subscribe to the RSS feed



To comment, please register for free with FT.com and read our policy on submitting comments.

All posts are published in UK time.

See the full list of FT blogs.

What we’re writing about

Afghanistan Asia maritime tensions carbon central banks China climate change Crimea emerging markets energy EU European Central Bank George Osborne global economy inflation Japan Pakistan quantitative easing Russia Rwanda security surveillance Syria technology terrorism UK Budget UK economy Ukraine unemployment US US Federal Reserve US jobs Vladimir Putin

Categories

Africa America Asia Britain Business China Davos Europe Finance Foreign Policy Global Economy Latin America Markets Middle East Syria World

Archive

« Sep Nov »October 2011
M T W T F S S
 12
3456789
10111213141516
17181920212223
24252627282930
31